Wade et al. (2008): Ecological restoration of farmland: progress and prospects

On 8th October 2010 we discussed a review article by Wade et al. (2008) on farmland ecological restoration. The authors suggest that ecological restoration projects may become necessary in farmlands in the course of the continuing expansion of agricultural production, in order to secure the functioning of related ecosystem services in the future. The authors also discuss where, when and how ecological restoration projects have been, and could be, implemented. The article was a useful read to at least some of us, since we were so well familiar with the topic, even though changes in agriculture could have a remarkable influence on biodiversity conservation.

The major issue that raised discussion in the journal club was that the role given to biodiversity in the article: the authors assessed the value of biodiversity and the threat of its depletion mainly as how biodiversity benefits the human society via ecosystem services. We recognize the term ‘ecosystem services’ as today’s buzzword, with much of the ‘buzz’ focusing on the quantification of the monetary value of ecosystem services. While we can see the benefit of approximating the scale of human economic benefit from the existence of natural ecosystems, we raised several concerns over this quantification trend from the perspective of species conservation:

  1. It is important to keep in mind that restoring ecosystems by using ecosystem services as indicators of success does not necessarily have much to do with the conservation of native biodiversity. This is exemplified by the authors of this article, as they present cases where ecosystem functions have been enhanced along with the ecological fitting of exotic species, and while they state that “relatively large increases in ecosystem function may be achieved with low or modest levels of biodiversity enhancement”.
  2. Studying ecosystems as sets of measurable, categorised services may blur our perception on how complex natural ecosystems are, and how difficult it may be to accomplish a systemic change in ecosystem function that would be truly stable in the long run.
  3. Giving simple price tags to ecosystem services easily hides the subjectivity of the underlying quantifications. Is there just one way to measure, for instance, the monetary value of pollination to the human society?

While the article focused heavily on ecosystem services, its views on how ecosystem restoration projects support species conservation goals became unclear. The authors stated that there is no worldwide compendium of species that have been targeted in farmland ecological restoration programmes. Species of native ecosystems that have been displaced by agriculture were mentioned as potential targets, but the species known to be dependent on traditional agricultural landscapes were mostly bypassed. The overall goal of “restoring ecosystem ‘health’“ did not quite fit together with the artificiality of examples where, for instance, forest-dwelling insects were supported in agricultural landscapes with added coarse woody debris.

The lack of well-founded conservation goals makes it difficult to evaluate which restoration methods would make sense from conservation point of view. For instance, if the Earth’s land surface area required by agriculture is indeed going to rise to 60 %, some species would probably benefit from it consisting of patchy landscapes full of corridors, edges and nodes, as the authors suggest. But many species of native ecosystems might also suffer from such means of restoration, as they would rather benefit from agricultural landscapes being as compact as possible, which would leave the maximum possible space for continuous, natural ecosystems elsewhere.

Nevertheless, there is a great need for an exchange of views between agro-economics and conservation biology. This very comprehensive, cross-disciplinary article was a welcome element to that discussion.

Link to the paper:

Wade M, Gurr G & Wratten S (2008): Ecological restoration of farmland: progress and prospects. — Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 363:831-847.

Juutinen et al. (2008): Cost-effective forest conservation and criteria for potential conservation targets: a Finnish case study

This article was very different from our other read articles. The viewpoint of it was more commercial forestry than ecology or biodiversity of which we have often been used to. And as we found out this article was part of Biodiversity and Monitoring program in Finland (MOSSE) it was interesting to see what else is there.

General observation was that biodiversity and ecology aspects were quite well forgotten even though we thought that this article would contain them. We were surprised as well that the content seemed to ignore the enormous literature, research work and case studies of different spatial analysis tools and techniques and their use. The article was written in very detailed way so that many of us thought it was too long. The obverse is that for example the materials, which are the same that are used in many similar studies, were explained so that everyone know now where they came from. Even the article was long it left a questions unanswered in cases such How did they really count the habitat index, why don’t they discuss the ratio between patch quality and size, what really is the budget etc.. The variables comes from commercial forestry and in this article it’s very poorly or not at all described that they have an impact on quality as well, not only to productivity.

Main message of the paper seemed to be that there’s no need to conserve the “best” places (for example with richest biodiversity) because if we choose less good they will eventually become better and in the end the result will be the same. The writers don’t mention anything about where the species which are now living in the best places would stay waiting for time to do its magic in these less good areas.

The second message is that according to their modeling there’s not enough good quality forests left in the survey area and therefore the target boundary could be set lower to
1. be able to achieve target (for example to conserve 10% of the area)
2. save money because bigger areas could be chosen and the bigger the area is the cheaper the conservation is per unit in this case.

For us – people working with mainly in “conservation science” world – the article was an awakening experience about other perspectives in conservation, preservation and the value of biodiversity among other policymakers and scientists.

——————————
Journal Club 11.6.2010.

Cost-effective forest conservation and criteria for potential conservation targets: a Finnish case study: Juutinen, A., Lugue, S., Mönkkönen, M., Vainikainen, N., Tomppo, E.

Environmental Science & Policy
Volume 11, Issue 7, November 2008, Pages 613-626

http://www.sciencedirect.com/science?_ob=ArticleURL&_udi=B6VP6-4SWG0NT-1&_user=949111&_coverDate=11%2F30%2F2008&_rdoc=1&_fmt=high&_orig=search&_sort=d&_docanchor=&view=c&_searchStrId=1370206143&_rerunOrigin=scholar.google&_acct=C000049116&_version=1&_urlVersion=0&_userid=949111&md5=b418672bbd4ba14c146c118d2fb1a2da

Gowdy et al. 2010: What every conservation biologist should know about ecenomic theory

This essay was an interesting piece of reading, although it did not quite deliver what the title promised: We were hoping for an “abc for dummies” kind of a paper, literally explaining what every conservation biologist should know about economic theory. Instead, the essay largely focused on criticizing the Walrasian model of economics that underlies much of  modern econimical thinking. It very well described all its flaws and inconsistencies with the real world, but it did not seem so specifically targeted to conservaion biologists.

The paper had a strong focus on critique, with little about alternatives, such as ecological or biophysical economics, that are mentioned, but nothing else. This essay would have been an excellend opportunity to give a brief introduction to what those relatively modern branches of economics actully are.

The authors emphasized how strongly current economic theory is based on the Walrasian foundation, even though it is so clearly flawed in many ways. Most of the flaws appear to have been recognized already a long time ago, but with little influence to the practice. It would have been nice to be able to discuss the paper with an economist to get an idea of how well these problems are recognized among researchers in economic theory, people applying theory to practice in one way or another, and among politics. We at least would guess the last group to be the most ignorant about these issues, but sadly also a very powerful group, imposing these dysfunctional principles in their everyday decision making.

In general, I at least was nevertheless happy to read this paper and agreed with its contents. It very nicely complements and deepens the discussion on what we were trying to say withour own essay just published in Cons Biol (DOI: 10.1111/j.1523-1739.2010.01539.x). Gowdy et al. provide a wealth of convincing evidence indicating the flaws of the free market, which in our layman version we tried to explain with help of the cebus monkey Mr. Monk. So it would have been nice to see this published together with ours, which unfortunately did not happen.

A memorable quote from the paper: “Since the scientific revolution began, scientists have made simplifying assumptions to make analysis tractable. But natural scienctists generally make sure their assumptions do not contradict reality”. 😀

DOI: 10.1111/j.1523-1739.2010.01563.x